AGAINST
MONEY
It is perplexing that France, for so long and so brilliantly at
the forefront of the arts, has recently produced very few gifted
people of note - except (but decreasingly) in the cinema and,
to a lesser extent, on the wilder shores of the social sciences.
One of the most varied and dynamic musical movements in Europe
expired after the deaths of Ravel and Poulenc, leaving only Messiaen
as a lone and minor voice - mainly because he was hardly influenced
by the 12-tone dead-hand and -end presented by the ghouls of IRCAM.
Picasso more or
less killed off subsequent French painters, so that no-one of
stature has appeared since Bonnard, Braque and Matisse. France
is full of commercial art galleries selling embarrassingly-bad
stuff at obscene prices - a fact which has a bearing on the article
below.
On the other hand,
ceramics, for long ignored, have recently enjoyed a wonderful
revival, due partly to influences from Britain, Germany and Japan.
They are wonderfully underpriced, presumably because they are
under-rated as mere 'craft' (artisanat).
Now, if it can free
itself from the dead hand of Trade Union socialism on the one
hand, and turbo-capitalism on the other, France is poised to lead
the world in social and moral philosophy - if anyone is around
to listen.
I suspect that the
reason for France's artistic decline lies in the savagely monoculturalist,
exam-obsessed, totalitarian education system set up in the early
days of the Third Republic by Jules Ferry.
The article below
was published online by www.freewords.org,
in a rather unreadable format. - which is why I reproduce it on
this website.
GIVE
IT AWAY
by
David
Graeber,
Reader in Social
Anthropology at Goldsmiths, University of London,
and author of : DEBT:
The First 5,000 years.
Have you
noticed how there aren't any new French intellectuals any more?
There was a veritable flood in the late '70s and early '80s: Derrida,
Foucault, Baudrillard, Kristeva, Lyotard, de Certeau ... but there
has been almost no one since. Trendy academics and intellectual
hipsters have been forced to endlessly recycle theories now 20
or 30 years old, or turn to countries like Italy or even Slovenia
for dazzling meta-theory.
There are a lot
of reasons for this. One has to do with politics in France itself,
where there has been a concerted effort on the part of media elites
to replace real intellectuals with American-style empty-headed
pundits. Still, they have not been completely successful. More
important, French intellectual life has become much more politically
engaged. In the U.S. press, there has been a near blackout on
cultural news from France since the great strike movement of 1995,
when France was the first nation to definitively reject the "American
model" for the economy, and refused to begin dismantling
its welfare state. In the American press, France immediately became
the silly country, vainly trying to duck the tide of history.
Of course this in
itself is hardly going to faze the sort of Americans who read
Deleuze and Guattari. What American academics expect from France
is an intellectual high, the ability to feel one is participating
in wild, radical ideas - demonstrating the inherent violence
within Western conceptions of truth or humanity, that sort of
thing - but in ways that do not imply any program of political
action; or, usually, any responsibility to act at all. It's easy
to see how a class of people who are considered almost entirely
irrelevant both by political elites and by 99 percent of the general
population might feel this way. In other words, while the U.S.
media represent France as silly, U.S. academics seek out those
French thinkers who seem to fit the bill.
As a result, some
of the most interesting scholars in France today you never hear
about at all. One such is a group of intellectuals who go by the
rather unwieldy name of Mouvement Anti-Utilitariste dans les Sciences
Sociales, or MAUSS, and who have dedicated themselves to a systematic
attack on the philosophical underpinnings of economic theory.The
group take their inspiration from the great early-20th century
French sociologist Marcel Mauss, whose most famous work, The
Gift (1925), was perhaps the most magnificent refutation
of the assumptions behind economic theory ever written. At a time
when "the free market" is being rammed down everyone's
throat as both a natural and inevitable product of human nature,
Mauss' work - which demonstrated not only that most non-Western
societies did not work on anything resembling market principles,
but that neither do most modern Western ones - is more relevant
than ever. While francophile American scholars seem unable to
come up with much of anything to say about the rise of global
neo-liberalism, the MAUSS group is attacking its very foundations.
A word of background.
Marcel Mauss was born in 1872 to an Orthodox Jewish family in
[the département of] Vosges. His uncle, Émile
Durkheim, is considered the founder of modern sociology. Durkheim
surrounded himself with a circle of brilliant young acolytes,
among whom Mauss was appointed to study religion. The circle,
however, was shattered by World I; many died in the trenches,
including Durkheim's son, and Durkheim himself died of grief shortly
thereafter. Mauss was left to pick up the pieces.
By all accounts,
though, Mauss was never taken completely seriously in his role
of heir apparent; a man of extraordinary erudition (he knew at
least a dozen languages, including Sanskrit, Maori and classical
Arabic), he still, somehow, lacked the gravity expected of a grand
professeur. A former amateur boxer, he was a burly man with
a playful, rather silly manner, the sort of person always juggling
a dozen brilliant ideas rather than building great philosophical
systems. He spent his life working on at least five different
books (on prayer, on nationalism, on the origins of money, etc.),
none of which he ever finished. Still, he succeeded in training
a new generation of sociologists and inventing French anthropology
more or less single-handedly, as well as in publishing a series
of extraordinarily innovative essays, just about each one of which
has generated an entirely new body of social theory all by itself.
Mauss was also a
revolutionary socialist. From his student days on he was a regular
contributor to the left press, and remained most of his life an
active member of the French co-operative movement. He founded
and for many years helped run a consumer co-op in Paris; and was
often sent on missions to make contact with the movement in other
countries (for which purpose he spent time in Russia after the
revolution). Mauss was not a Marxist, though. His socialism was
more in the tradition of Robert Owen or Pierre-Joseph Proudhon:
He considered Communists and Social Democrats to be equally misguided
in believing that society could be transformed primarily through
government action. Rather, the role of government, he felt, was
to provide the legal framework for a socialism that had to be
built from the ground up, by creating alternative institutions.
The Russian revolution
thus left him profoundly ambivalent. While exhilarated by prospects
of a genuine socialist experiment, he was outraged by the Bolsheviks'
systematic use of terror, their suppression of democratic institutions,
and most of all by their "cynical doctrine that the end
justifies the means," which, Mauss concluded, was really
just the amoral, rational calculus of the marketplace, slightly
transposed.
Mauss' essay on
"the gift" was, more than anything, his response
to events in Russia - particularly Lenin's New Economic Policy
of 1921, which abandoned earlier attempts to abolish commerce.
If the market could not simply be legislated away, even in Russia,
probably the least monetarized European society, then clearly,
Mauss concluded, revolutionaries were going to have to start thinking
a lot more seriously about what this "market" actually
was, where it came from, and what a viable alternative to it might
actually be like. It was time to bring the results of historical
and ethnographic research to bear.
Mauss' conclusions
were startling. First of all, almost everything that "economic
science" had to say on the subject of economic history turned
out to be entirely untrue. The universal assumption of free market
enthusiasts, then as now, was that what essentially drives human
beings is a desire to maximize their pleasures, comforts and material
possessions (their "utility"), and that all significant
human interactions can thus be analyzed in market terms. In the
beginning, goes the official version, there was barter. People
were forced to get what they wanted by directly trading one thing
for another. Since this was inconvenient, they eventually invented
money as a universal medium of exchange. The invention of further
technologies of exchange (credit, banking, stock exchanges) was
simply a logical extension.
The problem was,
as Mauss was quick to note, there is no reason to believe a society
based on barter has ever existed. Instead, what anthropologists
were discovering were societies where economic life was based
on utterly different principles, and most objects moved back and
forth as gifts - and almost everything we would call "economic"
behavior was based on a pretense of pure generosity and a refusal
to calculate exactly who had given what to whom. Such "gift
economies" could on occasion become highly competitive, but
when they did it was in exactly the opposite way from our own:
Instead of vying to see who could accumulate the most, the winners
were the ones who managed to give the most away. In some notorious
cases, such as the Kwakiutl of British Columbia, this could lead
to dramatic contests of liberality, where ambitious chiefs would
try to outdo one another by distributing thousands of silver bracelets,
Hudson Bay blankets or Singer sewing machines, and even by destroying
wealth - sinking famous heirlooms in the ocean, or setting
huge piles of wealth on fire and daring their rivals to do the
same.
All of this may
seem very exotic. But as Mauss also asked: How alien is it, really?
Is there not something odd about the very idea of gift-giving,
even in our own society? Why is it that, when one receives a gift
from a friend (a drink, a dinner invitation, a compliment), one
feels somehow obliged to reciprocate in kind? Why is it that a
recipient of generosity often somehow feels reduced if he or she
cannot? Are these not examples of universal human feelings, which
are somehow discounted in our own society - but in others
were the very basis of the economic system? And is it not the
existence of these very different impulses and moral standards,
even in a capitalist system such as our own, that is the real
basis for the appeal of alternative visions and socialist policies?
Mauss certainly felt so.
In a lot of ways
Mauss' analysis bore a marked resemblance to Marxist theories
about alienation and reification being developed by figures like
György Lukács around the same time. In gift economies,
Mauss argued, exchanges do not have the impersonal qualities of
the capitalist marketplace: In fact, even when objects of great
value change hands, what really matters is the relations between
the people; exchange is about creating friendships, or working
out rivalries, or obligations, and only incidentally about moving
around valuable goods. As a result everything becomes personally
charged, even property: In gift economies, the most famous objects
of wealth - heirloom necklaces, weapons, feather cloaks -
always seem to develop personalities of their own.
In a market economy
it's exactly the other way around. Transactions are seen simply
as ways of getting one's hands on useful things; the personal
qualities of buyer and seller should ideally be completely irrelevant.
As a consequence everything, even people, start being treated
as if they were things too. (Consider in this light the expression
"goods and services.") The main difference with Marxism,
however, is that while Marxists of his day still insisted on a
bottom-line economic determinism, Mauss held that in past market-less
societies - and by implication, in any truly humane future
one - "the economy," in the sense of an autonomous
domain of action concerned solely with the creation and distribution
of wealth, and which proceeded by its own, impersonal logic, would
not even exist.
Mauss was never
entirely sure what his practical conclusions were. The Russian
experience convinced him that buying and selling could not simply
be eliminated in a modern society, at least "in the foreseeable
future," but a market ethos could. Work could be co-operatized,
effective social security guaranteed and, gradually, a new ethos
created whereby the only possible excuse for accumulating wealth
was the ability to give it all away. The result: a society whose
highest values would be "the joy of giving in public, the
delight in generous artistic expenditure, the pleasure of hospitality
in the public or private feast."
Some of this may
seem awfully naïve from today's perspective, but Mauss' core
insights have, if anything, become even more relevant now than
they were 75 years ago - now that economic "science"
has become, effectively, the revealed religion of the modern age.
So it seemed, anyway, to the founders of MAUSS.
The idea for MAUSS
was born in 1980. The project is said to have emerged from a conversation
over lunch between a French sociologist, Alain Caillé,
and a Swiss anthropologist, Gérald Berthoud. They had just
sat through several days of an interdisciplinary conference on
the subject of gifts, and after reviewing the papers, they came
to the shocked realization that it did not seem to have occurred
to a single scholar in attendance that a significant motive for
giving gifts might be, say, generosity, or genuine concern for
another person's welfare. In fact, the scholars at the conference
invariably assumed that "gifts" do not really exist:
Scratch deep enough behind any human action, and you'll always
discover some selfish, calculating strategy. Even more oddly,
they assumed that this selfish strategy was always, necessarily,
the real truth of the matter; that it was more real somehow than
any other motive in which it might be entangled. It was as if
to be scientific, to be "objective" meant to be completely
cynical. Why?
Caillé ultimately
came to blame Christianity. Ancient Rome still preserved something
of the older ideal of aristocratic open-handedness: Roman magnates
built public gardens and monuments, and vied to sponsor the most
magnificent games. But Roman generosity was also quite obviously
meant to wound: One favorite habit was scattering gold and jewels
before the masses to watch them tussle in the mud to scoop them
up. Early Christians, for obvious reasons, developed their notion
of charity in direct reaction to such obnoxious practices. True
charity was not based on any desire to establish superiority,
or favor, or indeed any egoistic motive whatsoever. To the degree
that the giver could be said to have gotten anything out of the
deal, it wasn't a real gift.
But this in turn
led to endless problems, since it was very difficult to conceive
of a gift that did not benefit the giver in any way. Even an entirely
selfless act would win one points with God. There began the habit
of searching every act for the degree to which it could be said
to mask some hidden selfishness, and then assuming that this selfishness
is what's really important. One sees the same move reproduced
so consistently in modern social theory. Economists and Christian
theologians agree that if one takes pleasure in an act of generosity,
it is somehow less generous. They just disagree on the moral implications.
To counteract this very perverse logic, Mauss emphasized the "pleasure"
and "joy" of giving: In traditional societies, there
was not assumed to be any contradiction between what we would
call self-interest (a phrase that, he noted, could not even be
translated into most human languages) and concern for others;
the whole point of the traditional gift is that it furthers both
at the same time.
These, anyway,
were the kind of issues that first engaged the small, interdisciplinary
group of French and French-speaking scholars (Caillé, Berthoud,
Ahmet Insel, Serge Latouche, Pauline Taieb) who were to become
MAUSS. Actually, the group itself began as a journal, called Revue
du MAUSS - a very small journal, printed sloppily on
bad paper - whose authors conceived it as much as an in-joke
as a venue for serious scholarship, the flagship journal for a
vast international movement that did not then exist. Caillé
wrote manifestos; Insel penned fantasies about great international
anti-utilitarian conventions of the future. Articles on economics
alternated with snatches from Russian novelists. But gradually,
the movement did begin to materialize. By the mid-'90s, MAUSS
had become an impressive network of scholars - ranging from
sociologists and anthropologists to economists, historians and
philosophers, from Europe, North Africa and the Middle East -
whose ideas had become represented in three different journals
and a prominent book series (all in French) backed up by annual
conferences.
Since the strikes
of 1995 and the election of a Socialist government, Mauss' own
works have undergone a considerable revival in France, with the
publication of a new biography and a collection of his political
writings. At the same time, the MAUSS group themselves have become
evermore explicitly political. In 1997, Caillé released
a broadside called "30 Theses for a New Left," and
the MAUSS group have begun dedicating their annual conferences
to specific policy issues. Their answer to the endless calls for
France to adopt the "American model" and dismantle its
welfare state, for example, was to begin promulgating an economic
idea originally proposed by American revolutionary Tom Paine:
the guaranteed national income. The real way to reform welfare
policy is not to begin stripping away social benefits, but to
reframe the whole conception of what a state owes its citizens.
Let us jettison welfare and unemployment programs, they said.
But instead, let us create a system where every French citizen
is guaranteed the same starting income (say, $20,000 or £13,000)
supplied directly by the government) - and then the rest
can be up to them.
It is hard to know
exactly what to make of the Maussian left, particularly insofar
as Mauss is being promoted now, in some quarters, as an alternative
to Marx. It would be easy to write them off as simply super-charged
social democrats, not really interested in the radical transformation
of society. Caillé's "30 Theses," for
example, agree with Mauss in conceding the inevitability of some
kind of market - but still, like him, look forward to the
abolition of capitalism, here defined as the pursuit of financial
profit as an end in itself. On another level, though, the Maussian
attack on the logic of the market is more profound, and more radical,
than anything else now on the intellectual horizon. It is hard
to escape the impression that this is precisely why American intellectuals,
particularly those who believe themselves to be the most wild-eyed
radicals, willing to deconstruct almost any concept except greed
or selfishness, simply don't know what to make of the Maussians
- why, in fact, their work has been almost completely ignored.
©
David Rolfe Graeber, MMXII |
|